14 February 2024

Tradeable Birth Certificates?

In Aidan Llewellyn trading as the Trustee for the House of Llewellyn v State of New South Wales [2023] NSWSC 1250 Kunc J analyses Llewellyn's pseudolaw claim that birth certificates are tradeable securities. 

Llewellyn among other matters claimed to be a '"bondholder" and expects full repayment of the face value of the securities".' Unsurprisingly the Court disagreed 

 Ms Dunlop's helpful submissions set out a number of reasons why, with great respect to the Plaintiff, the summons and the relief sought in it are completely misconceived as a matter of the laws applicable in New South Wales and, for that matter, the Commonwealth of Australia generally (Mr Llewellyn’s submissions appeared at one point to suggest a relevant distinction between state law and Commonwealth law). It is sufficient for me to deal with only two matters put by Ms Dunlop that are entirely dispositive of the Plaintiff’s claim. 

The first is the Plaintiff’s proposition that either in and of itself, or by reason of the process of registration and certification or authentication, Mr Llewellyn's birth certificate is a form of security. The Court accepts the State’s submission that the birth certificate is plainly no such thing. Apart from anything else, it contains no words of charge, mortgage, guarantee or similar that one would expect to see in a document that met the orthodox legal definition of a "security". It is a birth certificate, undoubtedly an important document, but on no view is it a security creating rights as such under any law of this country. 

The second fundamental difficulty with the Plaintiff’s case relied upon by the State appears from what I have set out in [16] above, which displays a basic misunderstanding of the expression "full faith and credit" where those words appear in s 118 of the Constitution (Cth) and in other legislation relied upon by the Plaintiff. 

The Plaintiff, fastening upon an online definition from "Investopedia", submits that "credit" in the expression “full faith and credit” is something to do with guaranteeing or evidencing a debt. There can be no doubt that is not the meaning of "credit" in the expression "full faith and credit". "Credit" in that phrase refers to the concept of acceptance or belief in the validity of something. 

The two reasons which I have identified are sufficient to demonstrate for the purposes of the State’s notice of motion that the summons discloses no reasonable cause of action and ought to be summarily dismissed accordingly. There is, in fact or law, no “Trust owned Security” about which any of the defendants can provide the information sought by the summons as explicated in the “petition”. 

However, before leaving the substantive issues raised during the course of the hearing, I should also record that Mr Llewellyn "moved to strike" the State's submissions. He did so on the basis that those submissions were "non fact, hearsay, rhetoric, unwarranted, conjecture" and other epithets to like effect. 

As I sought to explain to Mr Llewellyn during the course of argument, submissions are not evidence and are not required to be sworn. The State’s motion was supported by an affidavit sworn by a solicitor with the conduct of the matter. The State’s submissions are something quite different from the affidavit in support. They are exactly that – submissions – and not evidence. I therefore rejected Mr Llewellyn's application "to strike" the State’s submissions. ... 

I invited Mr Llewellyn to put any submissions as to why he, being the named “petitioner, Aidan Rees Llewellyn as trustee for the House of Llewellyn”, should not be ordered to pay the State’s costs of the summons including the present motion. He responded that he should not be ordered to pay costs as he did not accept the validity of my judgment because of the various facts upon which the Plaintiff relied. He submitted those facts had not been controverted by the State and that my reasons were inadequate. 

This is a case where the usual principle should apply as to costs, namely that costs follow the event. Mr Llewellyn’s submissions do not provide a proper basis to depart from that position in the exercise of the Court’s discretion. The event is the dismissal of the summons in accordance with the State’s notice of motion. The Court will order that the Plaintiff pay the State’s costs of the summons, including of the State’s notice of motion, and make directions for the resolution of the application for costs on a gross sum basis.

Competition, Rockets and Feathers

The 'Gouging' report from Alan Fels for the ACTU comments 

This report concludes that business pricing has added significantly to inflation in recent times. 

‘Profit push’ or ‘sellers inflation’ has occurred against a background of high corporate concentration and is reflected in the surge of corporate profits and the rise in the profit share of Gross Domestic Product. There is much support for the view that prices have added much to inflation. This is to be found in research from OECD, IMF, BIS, European Commission, European Central Bank, US Federal Reserve Bank, Bank of England and many think tanks globally and locally and many detailed research studies. Claims that the rise in profit share in Australia as explained by mining do not hold up. The profits share excluding mining has risen and energy and other prices associated with mining have been a very significant contributor to Australian inflation. ... 

The report analyses a selection of exploitative business pricing practices that enable the extraction of extra dollars from consumers in a way that would not be possible in markets that are competitive, properly informed and that enable overcharged consumers to readily switch from one supplier to another. The fact that there is a quite widespread lack of competition in Australian markets means that pricing practices that might be accepted in very competitive markets are unduly exploitative of consumers in that setting.

 Fels identifies a range of 'not unlawful' practices 

 Loyalty taxes set initial prices low and then sharply increase them in subsequent years when consumers cannot easily detect, question, or renegotiate them and where the ‘transaction costs’ of changing to other competitors are high. Examples come from banking, insurance, energy, and other areas. 

Loyalty schemes are often low cost means of retaining and exploiting consumers by providing them with low value rewards of dubious benefit. These schemes are also often badly run. 

Drip pricing where firms only advertise part of a product’s price and reveal other prices later as the customer goes through the buying process is spreading including in airlines, accommodation, entertainment, pre-paid phone charges, credit cards and others. 

Excuse-flation where general inflation provides camouflage for businesses to raise prices without justification is also more prevalent in the current environment. As inflation starts to fall excessive inflationary expectations and future cost increases can be built into prices. 

Confusion pricing involves confusing consumers with a myriad of complex price structures and plans making price comparisons difficult and dulling price competition. It occurs more and more in areas such as telecommunications, financial or maintenance services and other fields. 

Asymmetric or ‘rockets and feathers’ pricing is of much concern in the current environment especially as inflation is starting to come down. When costs rise prices go up quickly ‘like a rocket’ but when costs fall prices fall slowly ‘like a feather falling to the ground’. This practice of delaying price falls when costs have fallen can be very profitable for businesses. A recent example concerned meat prices when prices paid to farmers for lamb fell but retail prices did not, at least until there was publicity including from this inquiry about the delay. 

Algorithmic pricing is the practice of using algorithms to set prices automatically (but taking account of competitor responses) raises issues about whether this reduces price competition and is analogous to cartel pricing. Price discrimination which in its simplest form involves charging different consumers different prices for the same product enables businesses to set prices according to how much each consumer is willing and able to pay. It takes many forms. It is enabled by a lack of competition. If there were competition charging high prices to customers who wish to or have to pay higher prices would not be possible because competitors would bring those prices down to normal levels. 

This report identifies a number of examples ranging from banks (better rates from customers likely to leave them), electricity (better prices for business customers than for consumers even allowing for lower costs of supply) and medical specialists which offer vastly different prices for near identical services. Of particular concern is the rise of much greater use of price discrimination enabled by the rise of digital platforms, new technology, detailed customer data and sophisticated profit maximising pricing methodologies. These practices all result from an economy which is insufficiently competitive and gives room for businesses to engage in exploitative pricing practices. There is a case for a much more active public policy for investigating and analysing practices that operate at unwarranted cost to customers. 

In order to address these the report recommends policy outcomes which would:

• remove obstacles to competition by the application of competition law or a removal of government restrictions on competition 

• require the provision of better information to consumers 

• lessen or remove obstacles to consumers switching to other suppliers 

• exposing or sometimes shaming exploitative business practices of the kind shown in this report 6

All these business exploitative practices rest on a platform of weak competition in many parts of the economy and would be generally reduced by a strengthening of competition law and policy. Accordingly, recommendations to this effect are made in the report. The prices practices described are not unlawful, but they reflect an imbalance between consumers and the power of business. Price control is not seen as a solution in most or all cases. However, there is a case for governments exercising much closer scrutiny over these practices and for such scrutiny to be a regular part of the policy agenda.

 Fels' recommendations are summarised as

1.1: The Australian Government should use its power to require the ACCC to conduct more price and market investigations. 

1.2: The Australian Government should have power to require the ACCC to undertake market studies as well as price studies. 

1.3: The ACCC should have power of its own to initiate price and market studies. 

1.4: The GST pricing legislation of 2000-2003 provisions regarding the naming of businesses and industries that overcharge should be reinstated. 

1.5: Section 46 of the Australian Competition and Consumer Act should be amended to make it an offence to charge excessive prices in terms similar to the European Union provisions. 

1.6: The Government could establish a Commission on Competition and Prices to review Government and other restrictions on competition and high prices caused by a lack of competition. 

MERGERS AND DIVESTITURE 

2.1: The Australian government should establish a pre-merger notification system along similar lines to most OECD countries. 

2.2: That in merger matters the onus should be on applicants to satisfy the ACCC and on appeal the Australian Competition Tribunal that the merger is not anticompetitive and is in the public interest. 

2.3: The merger test should be augmented to continue to prohibit mergers which substantially lessen competition but there should be an additional provision prohibiting mergers that give rise to substantial market power (a more structural and immediate test) and/or which entrench, create, or add to market power. 

2.4: A divestiture power should be introduced into the competition law. 

COMPETITION 

3.1: The Australian Consumer and Competition Act needs to be shortened. 

3.2: If the secondary boycott law is retained in the Competition Law there should be a provision that secondary boycotts are only unlawful if they substantially lessen competition. 

3.3: Australia should ban non-compete clauses in employment contracts affecting both employees during and post-employment. 

3.4: The current National Competition Review should examine policies and laws that prevent Governments from needlessly restricting competition. 

3.5: The ACCC receives further funding for strong enforcement of the cartel law. It should also apply the criminal sanctions available for unlawful price fixing and other cartel agreements. 

3.5: Treasury should conduct a public consultation to determine the need for improvement in the drafting of the criminal elements of the cartel law in view of recent difficulties in the bank cartel case. 

AVIATION 

4.1: Airport prices should be regulated in the same way as other utility prices. 

4.2: The Australian Government should use the opportunity of its current aviation review to remove international and domestic restrictions on competition. Any remaining restrictions should be reviewed by the Treasury led Competition Policy Review. 

EARLY CHILDHOOD EDUCATION AND CARE 

4.3: The ACCC should be empowered to investigate pricing decisions made by for-profit providers to ensure gaming is not occurring. 

4.4: Prices in relation to disability care and support and aged care should be kept under continuous review by the ACCC. 

BANKING AND FINANCIAL SERVICES 

4.5: The ACCC should be provided with a standing Ministerial Direction to monitor prices and competitiveness in the retail banking sector. 

4.6: The ACCC should be issued with a Ministerial Direction to undertake a further inquiry into pricing practices in foreign exchange markets to develop mechanisms for a fairer transmission of cost information to consumers as well as to provide specific assistance to prevent exploitation of those with low English language proficiency. 

ENERGY 

4.7: There should be a review of the design and operation of the wholesale market as to whether it requires refinements or a fundamental change in the form of a ‘capacity market’ as in North America and in Western Australia. This review should be chaired by an independent expert with input and resources from the AER, AEMO, and ASIC. The level of electricity generation concentration should be kept under review, and there should be close scrutiny of the impact on competition, positive or negative, that could occur in the transition to a re-designed energy market. 

4.8: ASIC should be provided with a Ministerial Direction to investigate the energy derivatives market to ensure that participants in both the National Electricity Market and the markets for derivatives are not misusing their position in either to gain an unfair advantage or influence the price of energy to meet derivatives conditions. 

4.9: Network prices should continue to require close regulatory scrutiny with the long-term interests of consumers put first. 

4.10: There should be a regulatory review of the high degree of price discrimination in the retail electricity and gas markets. 

4.11: State Governments and regulators should continue to introduce initiatives to improve retail outcomes brought about by current market imperfections. 

FOOD AND GROCERIES 

4.12: It is recommended that there should be a comprehensive ACCC inquiry into competition and prices in the retail food and grocery industry. 

4.13: The Food and Grocery Code Review should be fully mandatory. 

4.14: The Food and Grocery Code Review should investigate creating a price register for farmers to assist them in understanding market prices across primary industries. 

SHIPPING COSTS IMPACTING FNQ AND NT 

4.15: The ACCC should once again have an ability to challenge and overturn unreasonable prices charged by Sea Swift to ensure the service is not exploiting its market position. 

ELECTRIC VEHICLES 

4.16: Regulations in the Road Vehicle Safety Act 2018 which block parallel imports of electric vehicles be immediately lifted. 

4.17: Regulations under the Road Vehicle Safety Act 2018 which block parallel imports of cars into Australia should also be repealed in coming months. 

OUT OF POCKET CHARGES BY MEDICAL SPECIALISTS 

4.18: The National Competition policy review should conduct or commission a contemporary study of specialist fees backed by an analysis of restrictions on competition and of the role of information imbalances between patients and specialists. 

4.19: The ACCC or the Productivity Commission or another appropriate body should, separately, review specialist fees and the policy steps that could be taken to make them more transparent or to reduce them. 

PHARMACEUTICALS 

4.20: A mandatory reporting scheme should be implemented in relation to originator and generic agreements to improve the detectability of pay for delay agreements similar to the reporting arrangements in the United States.

Infrastructure

'The hardware turn in the digital discourse: an analysis, explanation, and potential risk' by Luciano Floridi in Philosophy and Technology comments 

The article examines the evolution of the digital discourse, indicating a paradigmatic shift from an immaterial to a material emphasis. Traditionally dominated by a focus on the intangible aspects of the digital—bits rather than atoms, especially software, data, services, experiences and interactions—the digital discourse is experiencing a hardware turn, which brings the infrastructure of digital technologies to the fore. The article elucidates how this transition expands the scope of digital ethics, encompassing the Governance, Ethical, Legal, and Social Implications (GELSI) of material components such as rare earth mineral mining, semiconductor production, datacentre operations, undersea cables and satellites. The interpretation defended is that the hardware turn is not the result of intellectual insights or scholarly advocacy but a response to political powers recognizing the strategic value of owning or controlling the material underpinnings of the digital domain (digital sovereignty). The article warns against the risk of swinging from an exclusively immaterial perspective to a solely material one, advocating for a relational ontology that focuses on the physical and social structures supporting the digital experience. y